|
[1]Arie, G., & Grieco, P. L. E. 2011, “Do Firms Compensate Switching Consumers?” [2]Beggs, A., & Klemperer, P. 1992, “Multi-period competition with switching costs.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp.651-666. [3]Bester, H., & Petrakis, E. 1996, “Coupons and oligopolistic price discrimination.” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol.14, no.2, pp.227-242. [4]Bouckaert, J., Degryse, H., & Provoost, T. 2011, “Enhancing market power by reducing switching costs.” Economics Letters. [5]Cabral, L. 2009, “Small switching costs lead to lower prices.” Journal of Marketing Research, vol.46, pp.449-451. [6]Caminal, R., & Matutes, C. 1990, “Endogenous switching costs in a duopoly model.” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol.8, no.3, pp.353-373. [7]Chen, Y. 1997, “Paying customers to switch.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, vol.6, no.4, pp.877-897. [8]Doganoglu, T. 2010, “Switching costs, experience goods and dynamic price competition.” Quantitative Marketing and Economics, vol.8, no.2, pp.167-205. [9]Dub, J.-P., Hitsch, G. J., & Rossi, P. E. 2009. “Do Switching Costs Make Markets Less Competitive?” Journal of Marketing Research, vol.46, no.4, pp.435-445. [10]Fabra, N., & García, A. 2012, “Dynamic Price Competition with Switching Costs.” [11]Farrell, J., & Klemperer, P. 2007, “Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects.” Handbook of industrial organization, vol.3, pp.1967-2072. [12]Farrell, J., & Shapiro, C. 1988, “Dynamic competition with switching costs.” The RAND Journal of Economics, pp.123-137. [13]Hotelling, H. 1929, “Stability in competition.” The economic journal, vol.39, no.153, pp.41-57. [14]Jones, M. A., Mothersbaugh, D. L., & Beatty, S. E. 2000, “Switching barriers and repurchase intentions in services.” Journal of retailing, vol.76, no2, pp.259-274. [15]Klemperer, P. 1987a, “Markets with consumer switching costs.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.102, no.2, pp.375. [16]Klemperer, P. 1987b, “The competitiveness of markets with switching costs.” The RAND Journal of Economics, pp.138-150. [17]Klemperer, P. 1995, “Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade.” The Review of Economic Studies, vol.62, no.4, pp.515. [18]Nilssen, T. 1992, “Two kinds of consumer switching costs.” The Rand Journal of Economics, pp.579-589. [19]Padilla, A. J. 1992, “Mixed pricing in oligopoly with consumer switching costs.” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol.10, no.3, pp.393-411. [20]Padilla, A. J. 1995, “Revisiting dynamic duopoly with consumer switching costs.” Journal of Economic Theory, vol.67, no.2, pp.520-530. [21]Pfeiffer, T. 2010, “A dynamic model of supplier switching.” European Journal of Operational Research, vol.207, no.2, pp.697-710. [22]Shaffer, G., & Zhang, Z. J. 2000, “Pay to Switch or Pay to Stay: Preference‐Based Price Discrimination in Markets with Switching Costs.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, vol.9, no.3, pp.397-424. [23]Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. R. 1999, Information rules: a strategic guide to the network economy: Harvard Business Press. [24]Shy, O. 2001, The economics of network industries: Cambridge Univ Pr. [25]Viard, V. B. 2007, “Do switching costs make markets more or less competitive? The case of 800‐number portability.” The Rand Journal of Economics, vol.38, no1, pp.146-163. [26]Villas-Boas, J. M. 1999, “Dynamic competition with customer recognition.” The RAND Journal of Economics, pp.604-631. [27]Von Weizsäcker, C. C. 1984, “The costs of substitution”. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp.1085-1116.
|