|
[1] Arifovic, J. and M. Maschek (2003), “Expectations and Currency Crisis–An Experimental Approach,” paper presented at the 9th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance, University of Washington, Seattle, July 11-13. [2] Arthur, W.B., J. Holland, B. LeBaron, R. Palmer, and P. Tayler (1997), “Asset Pricing under Endogenous Expectations in an Artificial Stock Market,” in W.B. Arthur, S. Durlauf and D. Lane (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II, Addison- Wesley, Reading, MA, pp. 15-44. [3] Barberis, N. and R. Thaler (2002), “A Survey of Behavioral Finance,” in G. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. Stulz (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, pp. 1051-1121. [4] Blume, L. and D. Easley (1992), “Evolution and Market Behavior,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 58, pp. 9-40. [5] Blume, L. and D. Easley (2001), “If You’re So Smart, Why Aren’t You Rich? Belief Selection in Complete and Incomplete Markets,” working paper. [6] Bullard, J. and J. Duffy (1999), “Using Genetic Algorithms to Model the Evolution of Heterogenous Beliefs,” Computational Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, pp. 41-60. [7] Chen, S.-H. and C.-H. Yeh (2001), “Evolving Traders and the Business School with Genetic Programming: A New Architecture of the Agent-based Artificial Stock Market,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 25, pp. 363-393. [8] Chen, S.-H. and Y.-C. Huang (2004), “Risk Preference, Forecasting Accuracy and Survival Dynamics: Simulations Based on a Multi-Asset Agent-Based Artificial Stock Market,”Working Paper Series 2004-1, AI-ECON Research Center, National Chengchi University. [9] Chen, S.-H. and Y.-C. Huang (2005a), “Risk Preference and Survival Dynamics,” in T. Terano, H. Kita, T. Kaneda and K. Arai (eds.), Agent-Based Simulation: From Modeling Methodologies to Real-World Applications, Springer Series on Agent-Based Social Systems, Springer, pp. 141-149. [10] Chen, S.-H. and Y.-C. Huang (2005b), “On the Role of Risk Preference in Survivability,” in Lipo Wang, Ke Chen, Yew S. Ong (eds.), Advances in Natural Computation, Lecture Notes in Computer Science 3612, Springer, pp. 612-621. [11] Constantinides, G. M., J, B. Donaldson, and R. Mehra (2002), “Junior Can’t Borrow: A New Perspective on the Equity Premium Puzzle,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.117, pp. 269-297. [12] Epstein, L. G. and S. E. Zin (1991), “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, pp. 263-286. [13] Feldman, J. (1962), “Computer Simulation of Cognitive Processes,” in H. Borko (ed.), Computer Applications in the Behavioral Sciences, Prentice Hall. [14] Friend, I. and M. E. Blume (1975), “The Demand for Risky Assets,” American Economic Review, Vol. 65, pp. 900-922. [15] Goldman, M. B. (1974), “A Negative Report on the ’Near Optimality’ of the Max- Expected-Log Policy as Applied to Bounded Utilities for Long Lived Programs,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 97-103. [16] Gordon, M. J. , G. E. Paradis and C. H. Rorke (1972), “Experimental Evidence on Alternative Portfolio Decision Rules,” American Economic Review, Vol. 62, pp. 107- 118. [17] Hansen, L. P. and K. Singleton (1982), “Generalized Instrumental Variables Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectation Models,” Econometrica,Vol. 50, pp. 1269-1286. [18] Holland, J. and J. Miller (1991), “Artificial Adaptive Agents in Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 2, pp. 365-370. [19] Huang, C. F. and R. H. Litzenberger (1988), Foundations for Financial Economics, Prentice Hall. [20] Jorion, P. and A. Giovannini (1993), “Time Series Tests of a Non-expected-Utility Model of Asset Pricing,” European Economic Review, Vol. 37, pp. 1083-1100. [21] Kandel, S. and R. F. Stambaugh (1991), “Asset Returns and Intertemporal Preferences,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 39-71. [22] Kelly, J. L. (1956), “A New Interpretation of Information Rate,” Bell System Technical Journal 35, pp. 917-926. [23] Laibson, D. (1998), “Life-Cycle Consumption and Hyperbolic Discount Functions,” European Economic Review, Vol. 42, pp. 861-871. [24] Lettau, M. (1997), “Explaining the Facts with Adaptive Agents: the Case of Mutual Fund Flows,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 21, No. 7, pp. 1117- 1147. [25] Lucas, D. (1994), “Asset Pricing with Undiversifiable Risk and Short Sales Constraints: Deepening the Equity Premium Puzzle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 34, pp. 325-341. [26] Luenberger, D. G. (1993), “A Preference Foundation for Log Mean-Variance Criteria in Portfolio Choice Problems,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 17, pp. 887-906. [27] Mankiw, G. N., J. J. Rotemberg, and L. H. Summers (1985), “Intertemporal Substitution in Macroeconomics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100, pp. 225-251. [28] Merton, R. C. and P. A. Samuelson (1974), “Fallacy of the Log-Normal Approximation to Optimal Portfolio Decision-Making over Many Periods,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 67-94. [29] Obstfeld, M. (1994), “Risk Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, pp. 1310-1329. [30] Rabin, M. (1998), “Psychology and Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, pp. 11-46. [31] Samuelson, P. A. (1970), “The Fundamental Approximation Theorem of Portfolio Analysis in terms of Means, Variances, and Higher Moments,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 537-542. [32] Samuelson, P. A. (1971), “The ’Fallacy’ of Maximizing the Geometric Mean in Long Sequences of Investing or Gambling,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 68, pp. 2493-2496. [33] Sandroni, A. (2000), “Do Markets Favor Agents Able to Make Accurate Predictions?” Econometrica, Vol. 68, No. 6, pp. 1303-1341. [34] Sciubba, E. (1999), “The Evolution of Portfolio Rules and the Capital Asset Pricing Model,” DAE Working Paper n. 9909, University of Cambridge. [35] Tay, N. and S. Linn (2001), “Fuzzy Inductive Reasoning, Expectation Formation and the Behavior of Security Prices,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 25, pp. 321-361. [36] Tesfatsion, L. (2001), “Introduction to the Special Issue on Agent-Based Computational Economics,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 25, pp. 281-293. [37] Tesfatsion, L. and K. L. Judd (2006), Handbook of Computational Economics Vol. 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics, North-Holland, forthcoming. [38] Vriend, N. J. (2000), “An Illustration of the Essential Difference between Individual and Social Learning, and its Consequences for Computational Analyses,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 24, pp. 1-19. [39] Zeldes, S. P. (1989), “Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, No. 2, pp. 305-346.
|